Adaptive Filter Theory 5th Edition Haykin Solutions Manualdownload
Adaptive Filter Theory 5th Edition Haykin Solutions Manualdownload
https://testbankfan.com/product/adaptive-filter-theory-5th-
edition-haykin-solutions-manual/
https://testbankfan.com/product/leadership-theory-application-and-
skill-development-5th-edition-lussier-solutions-manual/
https://testbankfan.com/product/auction-theory-2nd-edition-krishna-
solutions-manual/
https://testbankfan.com/product/accounting-theory-7th-edition-godfrey-
solutions-manual/
https://testbankfan.com/product/quickbooks-online-plus-a-complete-
course-2017-2nd-edition-horne-test-bank/
College Algebra Graphs and Models 6th Edition Bittinger
Test Bank
https://testbankfan.com/product/college-algebra-graphs-and-models-6th-
edition-bittinger-test-bank/
https://testbankfan.com/product/fundamentals-of-management-
canadian-8th-edition-robbins-test-bank/
https://testbankfan.com/product/american-government-15th-edition-
ansolabehere-test-bank/
https://testbankfan.com/product/college-algebra-4th-edition-blitzer-
solutions-manual/
https://testbankfan.com/product/strategic-management-a-competitive-
advantage-approach-concepts-15th-edition-david-test-bank/
Clinical Laboratory Hematology 2nd Edition McKenzie
Solutions Manual
https://testbankfan.com/product/clinical-laboratory-hematology-2nd-
edition-mckenzie-solutions-manual/
Other documents randomly have
different content
Harry Clowte. Gud conscience should them
move
Ther neighbours quietly to love,
And thus not for to wrynche
The commons styl for to pinch,
To take into their hande
That be other mennes land.
“We pray that the payments of castleward rent, and blanch ferm and
office lands, which hath been accustomed to be gathered of the
tenements, whereas we suppose the lords ought to pay the same to
their bailiffs for their rents gathering, and not the tenants.[595]
“We pray that no man under the degree of a knight or esquire keep a
dove house, except it hath been of an old ancient custom.
“We pray that all freeholders and copyholders may take the profits of
all commons, and there to common, and the lords not to common nor
to take profits of the same.
“We pray that no feudatory within your shires shall be a councellor to
any man in his office making, whereby the King may be truly served,
so that a man being of good conscience may be yearly chosen to the
same office by the commons of the same shire.
“We pray that all bondmen may be made free, for God made all free
with his precious bloodshedding.
“We pray that rivers may be free and common to all men for fishing
and passage.
“We pray that the poor mariners or Fishermen may have the whole
profits of their fishings, as porpoises, grampuses, whales, or any great
fish, so it be not prejudicial to your Grace.
“We pray that it be not lawful to the lords of any manor to purchase
land freely, or [and] to let them out again by copy of court roll to their
great advancement and to the undoing of your poor subjects.
“We pray that no man under the degree of ... shall keep any conies
upon any of their freehold or copyhold, unless he pale them in, so
that it shall not be to the common nuisance.
“We pray that your Grace give license and authority by your gracious
commission under your Great Seal to such commissioners as your
poor commons hath chosen, or to as many of them as your Majesty
and your Council shall appoint and think meet, for to redress and
reform all such good laws, statutes, proclamations, and all other your
proceedings, which hath been hidden by your justices of your peace,
shreves, escheators, and other your officers, from your poor
commons, since the first year of the reign of your noble grandfather,
King Henry VII.
“We pray that no lord, knight, esquire, nor gentleman, do graze nor
feed any bullocks or sheep, if he may spend forty pounds a year by
his lands, but only for the provision of his house.”
The programme of the peasants is partly political. The Northerners
insist that Parliament and the Crown must interfere, and the Norfolk
leaders ask for a permanent commission to do the work which the
county justices, who are interested in enclosing, have wilfully
neglected. But it is mainly economic. The State is to do no more than
restore the old usages, and the end of all is to be a sort of idealised
manorial customary enforced by a strong central Government
throughout the length of the land, free use of common lands, reduced
rents of meadow and marsh, reasonable fines for copyholds, free
fisheries, and the abolition of the lingering disability of personal
villeinage. The most striking thing about these demands is their
conservatism. Almost exactly a hundred years later agrarian reform
will be demanded as part of a new heaven and a new earth. Agrarian
agitation will be carried on in terms of theories as to the social
contract, of theories as to the origin of private property. Its leaders
will be appealing to Anglo-Saxon history to prove to the indifferent
ears of a Government which has saved them “from Charles, our
Norman oppressor,” that “England cannot be a free commonwealth,
unless the poore commoners have a use and benefit of the land.”[596]
They will appeal also to a more awful sanction than that of history. “At
this very day,” cries Winstanley,[597] “poor people are forced to work
for 4d. a day and corn is dear, and the tithing-priest stops their
mouths and tells them that 'inward satisfaction of mind' was meant by
the declaration 'the poor shall inherit the earth.' I tell you, the
scripture is to be really and materially fulfilled.... You jeer at the name
of Leveller. I tell you Jesus Christ is the head leveller." Such
communistic doctrines are always the ultimate fruit of the breakdown
of practical co-operation and brotherliness among men. To human
nature, as to other kinds of nature, a vacuum is abhorrent.
But as yet the soil has not been ploughed by a century of political and
religious controversy, and there is little sign of these high arguments
in the social disturbances of our period. The earliest levellers[598] get
their name because they raze not social inequalities but quickset
hedges and park palings. What communism there is in the movement
is not that of the saints or the theorists, but the spontaneous
doctrineless communism of the open field village, where men set out
their fields, and plough, and reap, laugh in the fine and curse in the
wet, with natural fellowship. The middle-class terror of the
appearance in England of the political theories of the German
Peasants' War, though it was forcibly expressed by Sir William
Paget[599] in remonstrating with Somerset's policy in 1549, and
though John Hales thought it worth while to repudiate it, is not
justified by any recorded utterances or programmes which have come
to us. There are, indeed, many verbal similarities between the articles
of Ket and those put out by the German peasants at Memmingen in
1525, which suggest that some refugee from Germany had carried
them with him to the most Protestant county in England. Both, for
example, demand a reduction in rents, the abolition of villeinage, and
free fisheries. But the contrasts are much more striking, and are due
not only to the fact that the onerous villein services which survived in
Germany had become almost nominal in England, but to the
difference in the spirit of their conception, which leads one to appeal
to the New Testament and the other to the customs of the first years
of Henry VII. There is, in fact, the same broad difference between the
peasant movements in England and Germany as there is between the
English and German Reformation. In Germany the ecclesiastical
changes spring from a widespread popular discontent, and are swept
forward on a wave of radical enthusiasm, which carries the peasants
(German Social Democrats are metaphysicians to this day) into the
revolutionary mysticism of Münzer. In England changes in Church
government are forced upon the people by the State, and outside the
South and East of England are regarded with abhorrence. It is not
until the later rise of Puritanism that either religious or economic
radicalism becomes a popular force. In the middle of the sixteenth
century the English peasants accepted the established system of
society with its hierarchy of authorities and division of class functions,
and they had a most pathetic confidence in the Crown. What they
wanted, in the first place, was fair conditions of land tenure, the
restoration of the customary relationships which had protected them
against the screw of commercial competition. When they went further,
they looked for an exercise of Royal Power to reduce to order the
petty tyranny of local magnates, and to carry out the intentions of a
Government which they were inclined to think meant them well, “to
redress and reform all such good laws, statutes, proclamations, and
all other your proceedings which hath been bidden by your justices of
your Peace ... from your poor commons.” Such movements are a
proof of blood and sinew and of a high and gallant spirit. They are the
outcome of a society where the normal relations are healthy, where
men are attached to the established order, where they possess the
security and control over the management of their own lives which is
given by property, and, possessing this, possess the reality of freedom
even though they stand outside the political state. Happy the nation
whose people has not forgotten how to rebel.
The social disturbances caused by enclosure, with its accompaniments
of rack-renting and evictions, were one cause which compelled the
Governments of our period to give attention to the subject. Though
no direct concessions were made to them, their lessons were not
altogether wasted, because it is plain that they impressed on the
minds of statesmen the idea that to prevent disorder it was necessary
for the State to interfere in favour of tenants. Rural discontent, which
might have been insignificant in an age of greater political stability,
derived a factitious importance from the circumstances of the
sixteenth century, when it might be exploited by a rebellious minority,
which, for all that most men knew, might really be a majority of the
nation, by Yorkist Plotters under Henry VII., religious enthusiasts
under Henry VIII., restorers of a Catholic monarchy, supported by a
Spanish invasion or a Franco-Scottish alliance, under Elizabeth.
Governments so uncertain of their popularity as these had a strong
reason for protecting the class which would be the backbone of a
revolt. One way in which they could secure themselves against the
discontent of the disaffected nobility was to encourage the yeomanry,
who might act as a counterpoise. The way in which self-preservation
and a popular agrarian policy went hand in hand is illustrated by
Burleigh’s cynical advice to Elizabeth to make a practice of supporting
tenants in any quarrel which might arise between them and Catholic
landlords.[600]
But there were other causes as well working in the same direction. No
one who reads the writers by whom the agrarian problem is discussed
can fail to notice that the official view of the proper system of
agrarian relationships was on the whole favourable to the small man,
and was, indeed, not very different from that expressed in the
demands of the peasants themselves. Not, of course, that the
authorities had any intention of depressing landlords or raising
peasants, but that the whole established system of Government was
based on a certain organisation of social life, and that the
Government tended to maintain that organisation in maintaining itself
and carrying on the work of the State. For this attitude, which is in
striking contrast with the policy of the statesmen of the eighteenth
century when faced with an analogous problem, there were several
practical reasons which we shall do well to understand. In judging the
motives of economic policy in past ages we are even more apt to be
misled by modern analogies than we are in estimating its effects. We
see that in our own day most of the legislative protection accorded to
those who are economically weak has been produced by a
combination of two causes, the political enfranchisement of the wage-
earning classes and the spread of humanitarian sentiment. We know
that in the sixteenth century the first cause was absent and the
second was feeble. The Macchiavellis of that iron age were neither
democrats nor philanthropists; and when they avow a policy of
protecting the weaker classes in society against economic evils we are
inclined to think with Professor Thorold Rogers that they are merely
hypocritical. But this analogy is a false light. To be influenced by it is
to confuse political power with its symbols, and to forget that the
economic importance of a class may be a more effective claim to the
interest of Governments than the ballot-box. Under the Tudors there
were strong practical reasons for protecting the peasantry which are
not felt to the same extent to-day. The modern State has so
specialised its organs that its maintenance is quite compatible with
the existence of the extremes of poverty, not only among the
exceptionally unfortunate, but among those whose position is not
more insecure than that of their neighbours. They may be able
neither to fight, nor to take part in public duties, nor to contribute
much to the Exchequer. But if their incompetence is a menace, it is a
menace which is not felt till after the lapse of generations, a menace
the fulfilment of which no single life is long enough to behold. For the
State hires specialists to fight, and specialists to keep order; indeed,
the poorer they are, the more cheaply it can obtain their services.[601]
Its local government is conducted mainly by specialised officials, and
the concentration of wealth makes possible a concentration of
taxation. The extension of political power has been accompanied by a
subdivision of political functions, which has diminished the importance
of the individual citizen, and turned him, as far as the routine of
Government is concerned, into a sleeping partner, whose consent is
necessary, but whose active co-operation is superfluous.
Now we need not point out that this would be as fair a description of
large classes of persons in the sixteenth century as it is now, and that
the day labourer and handicraftsman who “are to be ruled and not to
rule”[602] were, as a class, far more completely beneath the
consideration of statesmen than they are at the present day. But we
are concerned with the landholding population, not with the landless
wage-earner, and in the slightly differentiated state of our period both
economic and political conditions made a decline in the standard of
life among a class so important as the peasantry a danger which
might cause the most authoritarian of Governments to be confronted
with very grave practical difficulties. It might find itself unable to raise
an effective military force. The States of Continental Europe had
introduced standing armies. But England relied mainly on the shire
levies, and the shire levies were recruited from the small farmers. Just
as the lord of a manor in the North of England, whose tenants held by
border service with horse and harness, was anxious to prevent the
decline in their numbers which landlords elsewhere were welcoming,
so the Government regarded with quite genuine dismay an agrarian
movement which seemed to threaten its military resources by
impoverishing the finest fighting material in the country. Shadow,
Feeble, and Wart may “fill a pit as well as better"; but to make good
infantry it requires not “housed beggars,” but “men bred in some free
and plentiful manner." One Depopulation Statute after another recites
how “the defence of this land against our enemies outward is
enfeebled and impaired.”[603] In the settlement of the North after the
Pilgrimage of Grace the Government took care to instruct its officials
to see that the Northumbrian tenants, on whom the defence of the
border depended, “should be put in comfort, that no more shall be
exacted with gyrsums and like charges, instead of which they shall be
ready with horse and harness when required.”[604] In 1601 Cecil[605]
crushed a proposal to repeal the acts then in force against
depopulation by pointing out that the majority of the militia levies
were ploughmen. And in the instructions for the choice of persons to
be enrolled in the trained bands which were issued by the
Government of Charles I., particular care was taken to emphasise that
they were not to be selected at haphazard, but were to be drawn
from the families of the gentry, freeholders, and substantial farmers.
[606]
testbankfan.com